You signed in with another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You signed out in another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.You switched accounts on another tab or window. Reload to refresh your session.Dismiss alert
- $w_t$ is a wage or rental rate for labor at time $t$
200
+
- $w_t$ is a wage, i.e., a rental rate, for labor at time $t$
201
201
202
202
- $\eta_t$ is a rental rate for capital at time $t$
203
203
204
204
In addition there is a vector $\{q_t^0\}$ of intertemporal prices where
205
205
206
-
- $q^0_t$ is the price of a good at date $t$ relative
207
-
to a good at date $0$.
206
+
- $q^0_t$ is the price at time $0$ of one unit of the good at date $t$.
208
207
209
208
We call $\{q^0_t\}_{t=0}^T$ a vector of **Hicks-Arrow prices**,
210
209
named after the 1972 economics Nobel prize winners.
211
210
212
211
213
212
214
-
But because $q^0_t$ is a **relative price**, the units in terms of
215
-
which prices are quoted are arbitrary, we are free to re-normalize them by multiplying all of them by a positive scalar, say $\lambda > 0$.
213
+
Because is a **relative price**. the unit of account in terms of which the prices $q^0_t$ are stated is; we are free to re-normalize them by multiplying all of them by a positive scalar, say $\lambda > 0$.
216
214
217
-
Units of $q_t^0$ could be set so that
215
+
Units of $q_t^0$ could be set so that they are
218
216
219
217
$$
220
218
\frac{\text{number of time 0 goods}}{\text{number of time t goods}}
Components of a **price system** have the following units:
@@ -384,7 +382,7 @@ Components of a **price system** have the following units:
384
382
385
383
* $\eta_t$ is measured in units of the time $t$ good per unit of time $t$ capital hired
386
384
387
-
* $q_t^0$ is measured in units of the time $t$ good per unit of a numeraire
385
+
* $q_t^0$ is measured in units of a numeraire per unit of the time $t$ good
388
386
389
387
390
388
### Definitions
@@ -428,14 +426,22 @@ price system.
428
426
```{note}
429
427
This allocation will constitute the **Big** $K$ to be in the present instance of the **Big** $K$ **, little** $k$ trick
430
428
that we'll apply to a competitive equilibrium in the spirit of [this lecture](https://python.quantecon.org/rational_expectations.html)
431
-
and [this lecture](https://python-advanced.quantecon.org/dyn_stack.html).```
429
+
and [this lecture](https://python-advanced.quantecon.org/dyn_stack.html).
430
+
```
431
+
432
+
In particular, we shall use the following procedure:
432
433
433
-
In particular, we guess that for $t=0,\dots,T$:
434
+
* obtain first-order conditions for the representative firm and the representative consumer.
435
+
* from these equations, obtain a new set of equations by replacing the firm's choice variables $\tilde k, \tilde n$ and the consumer's choice variables with the quantities $\vec C, \vec K$ that solve the planning problem.
436
+
* solve the resulting equations for $\{\vec{q}, \vec{\eta}, \vec{w}\}$ as functions of $\vec C, \vec K$.
437
+
* verify that at these prices, $c_t = C_t, k_t = \tilde k_t = K_t, \tilde n_t = 1$ for $t = 0, 1, \ldots, T$.
Our approach is to stare at first-order necessary conditions for
506
+
Our approach is firsts to stare at first-order necessary conditions for
501
507
optimization problems of the household and the firm.
502
508
503
509
At the price system we have guessed, we'll then verify that both sets of first-order
@@ -652,12 +658,12 @@ identical to the one that solves the consumer's problem.
652
658
653
659
```{note}
654
660
Because budget sets are affected only by relative prices,
655
-
$\{q_0^t\}$ is determined only up to multiplication by a
661
+
$\{q^0_t\}$ is determined only up to multiplication by a
656
662
positive constant.
657
663
```
658
664
659
-
**Normalization:** We are free to choose a $\{q_0^t\}$ that
660
-
makes $\lambda=1$ so that we are measuring $q_0^t$ in
665
+
**Normalization:** We are free to choose a $\{q_t^0\}$ that
666
+
makes $\lambda=1$ so that we are measuring $q_t^0$ in
661
667
units of the marginal utility of time $0$ goods.
662
668
663
669
We will plot $q, w, \eta$ below to show these equilibrium prices
@@ -816,8 +822,9 @@ k_ss = pp.f_prime_inv(ρ+pp.δ)
816
822
c_ss = pp.f(k_ss) - pp.δ * k_ss
817
823
```
818
824
819
-
The above code from this lecture {doc}`Cass-Koopmans Planning Model <cass_koopmans_1>` lets us compute an optimal allocation for the planning problem that turns
820
-
out to be the allocation associated with a competitive equilibium.
825
+
The above code from this lecture {doc}`Cass-Koopmans Planning Model <cass_koopmans_1>` lets us compute an optimal allocation for the planning problem.
826
+
827
+
* from the preceding analysis, we know that it will also be an allocation associated with a competitive equilibium.
821
828
822
829
Now we're ready to bring in Python code that we require to compute additional objects that appear in a competitive equilibrium.
0 commit comments